IMF-能源补贴能帮助抑制通货膨胀吗?(英)_第1页
IMF-能源补贴能帮助抑制通货膨胀吗?(英)_第2页
IMF-能源补贴能帮助抑制通货膨胀吗?(英)_第3页
IMF-能源补贴能帮助抑制通货膨胀吗?(英)_第4页
IMF-能源补贴能帮助抑制通货膨胀吗?(英)_第5页
已阅读5页,还剩143页未读 继续免费阅读

下载本文档

版权说明:本文档由用户提供并上传,收益归属内容提供方,若内容存在侵权,请进行举报或认领

文档简介

CanEnergySubsidiesHelpSlayInflation?

ChristopherErceg,MarcinKolasa,JesperLinde,

andAndreaPescatori

WP/24/81

IMFWorkingPapersdescriberesearchin

progressbytheauthor(s)andarepublishedto

elicitcommentsandtoencouragedebate.

TheviewsexpressedinIMFWorkingPapersare

thoseoftheauthor(s)anddonotnecessarily

representtheviewsoftheIMF,itsExecutiveBoard,

orIMFmanagement.

2024

APR

N

Ann

R

INTERNATIONALMONETARYFUNDii

©2024InternationalMonetaryFund

WP/24/81

IMFWorkingPaper

MonetaryandCapitalMarketsDepartment

ResearchDepartment

CanEnergySubsidiesHelpSlayInflation?*

ChristopherErceg,MarcinKolasa,JesperLinde,AndreaPescatori

AuthorizedfordistributionbyChristopherErceg

April2024

IMFWorkingPapersdescriberesearchinprogressbytheauthor(s)andarepublishedtoelicit

commentsandtoencouragedebate.TheviewsexpressedinIMFWorkingPapersarethoseofthe

author(s)anddonotnecessarilyrepresenttheviewsoftheIMF,itsExecutiveBoard,orIMFmanagement.

ABSTRACT:Manycountrieshaveusedenergysubsidiestocushiontheeffectsofhighenergypricesonhouseholdsandfirms.AfterdocumentingthetransmissionofoilsupplyshocksempiricallyintheUnitedStatesandtheEuroArea,weuseaNewKeynesianmodelingframeworktostudytheconditionsunderwhichthesepoliciescancurbinflation.Wefirstconsideraclosedeconomymodeltoshowthataconsumersubsidymaybecounterproductive,especiallyasaninflation-fightingtool,whenappliedgloballyorinasegmentedmarket,atleastunderempiricallyplausibleconditionsaboutwage-setting.Wefindmorescopeforenergysubsidiestoreducecoreinflationandstimulatedemandifintroducedbyasmallgroupofcountrieswhichcollectivelydonothavemuchinfluenceonglobalenergyprices.However,theconditionsunderwhichconsumerenergysubsidiesreduceinflationarestillquiterestrictive,andthistypeofpolicymaywellbecounterproductiveiftheresultingincreaseinexternaldebtishighenoughtotriggersizeableexchangeratedepreciation.Sucheffectsaremorelikelyinemergingmarketswithshallowforeignexchangemarkets.Iftheprimarygoalofusingfiscalmeasuresinresponsetospikesinenergypricesistoshieldvulnerablehouseholds,thentargetedtransfersaremuchmoreefficientastheyachievetheirgoalsatlowerfiscalcostandtransmitlesstocoreinflation.

JELClassificationNumbers:E32,E52,E64,H23,Q43

Keywords:

EnergyPrices;EnergySubsidies;MonetaryPolicy;InternationalSpillovers

Author’sE-MailAddress:

CErceg@IMF.org,MKolasa@IMF.org,JLinde@IMF.org,andAPescatori@IMF.org

*WethankTianchuQiandKailiChenforexcellentresearchassistanceandTobiasAdrian,JaebinAhn,GiovanniDell'Ariccia,Pierre-OlivierGourinchas,ZoltanJakab,andMathiasTrabandtforusefulcommentsanddiscussions.ThepaperalsobenefitedfromcommentsfromtheparticipantstotheCEPRParisSymposium,ESSIMinTarragona,NBU-NBPARCinCracow,CEFinNice,SummerWorkshoponEconomicsandFinanceinWarsaw,andseminarsattheEuropeanCentralBank,Bancad'Italia,andUniversityofOttawa.TheviewsexpressedhereareoursanddonotnecessarilyrepresenttheviewsoftheIMF,itsExecutiveBoard,orIMFmanagement.

1

1Introduction

Centralbankshavetightenedmonetarypolicyaggressivelytocombathighinflation,whichsurgedtomulti-decadepeaksinmanyeconomies.Whiletheinflationrunuphasbeendrivenbyanumberoffactors,includingsupplydisruptionsandmassivefiscalandmonetarystimu-lus,sharpincreasesinenergypriceshavebeenamajorcatalyst.Manycountriesrespondedbyusingvariousformsofenergysubsidies,oftentargetedmainlytohouseholds,tohelpcurb

inflationaswellastocushiontheeffectsonhouseholdpurchasingpower(Arreguietal.

,

2022

;

Sgaravattietal.

,

2023).Energysubsidiesareviewedbymanypolicymakersashelpful

inthefightagainstinflationonthegroundsthattheyarelikelytolimitbothfirstandsecondroundeffects,includingbyreducingpassthroughtowages.

Buttherearemanyopenquestionsabouttheconditionsunderwhichenergysubsidiesareactuallylikelytobeeffectiveinloweringinflation,or,conversely,whentheymaybecoun-terproductive.Whilewagestickinesshaslongbeenrecognizedaspivotalinthetransmissionofenergyshockstooverallpriceinflation(e.g.,

BlanchardandGali

,

2007),therehasbeen

littleanalysisofhowtheeffectsofenergysubsidiesoninflationdependonthemodalitiesofwage-setting,includingthedegreeofindexation.Similarly,itisunclearhowtheeffectsofsubsidiesdependonthestructureoftheenergymarket:couldinsulatingconsumersfromtheeffectsofhigherpricesinahighlysegmentedmarket–suchastheonefornaturalgasinEurope–hurtfirmsenoughtocausecoreinflationtorise?Andhowdotheeffectsofsubsidiesdependonwhethertheyareusedbyasingle“smalleconomy”orabroadsetofcountries?

Inthispaper,weuseaNewKeynesianmodelingframeworktohelpanalyzetheseques-tions,butfirstseekempiricalgroundingbyestimatinghowoilshockstransmittotheeconomyintheUnitedStates(US)andeuroarea(EA).Specifically,weuseaproxySVARapproachwheretheinstrumentisgivenbysurprisechangesinoilpricesfollowingtheannouncementofOPECmeetingdecisions.Theseriesofsurprisesisadoptedfrom

Ka¨nzig

(2021)andaggre

-gatedtoquarterlyfrequencyoverthe1983to2019sampleperiod.Fortheseidentifiedshocks,wefindthatanegativeoilsupplyshockwhichdrivesupthepriceofoilleadstohighercoreandheadlineinflation,lowerGDP,andhigherpolicyratesinitiallyinboththeUSandtheeuroarea.Importantly,wefindsignificantdifferencesinthetransmissiontowagesbetweenthesetwoeconomies,withoilpricehikeshavingsmalleffectsonnominalwagesintheUS–sothatrealwagesfallnotably–whereastheytendtoboostnominalwagesenoughintheeuroareathatthereal(product)wageactuallyrises.Thesedifferencesinwagetransmissionturnouttohavecriticalbearingonhowenergysubsidiesaffectinflation.

Turningtoourtheoreticalframework,webeginbyconsideringasimpleworkhorseclosedeconomymodelwithnominalwageandpricestickinessthatbuildson

Bodensteinetal.

(2011)

.Asinthatmodel,weassumetheeconomyhasanendowmentofenergythatisutilizedbothinproductionandconsumption,butenrichthesupplyblockbyallowingfor

2

alternativeformsofdynamicwageindexationwherewagesmayadjusttoeithercoreorheadlineinflation.Wealsoincorporateenergysubsidiesthatareproportionaltoenergyuse,thusresemblingthedominanttypeofsubsidiesintroducedinmanycountries,includingtheUSandEurope.

Usingthismodel,wedemonstrateformallythatprovidingenergysubsidiestoconsumersisessentiallyequivalenttotaxingenergyusebyfirms:bothpoliciesdecreasetheeffectiveenergycosttohouseholdswhileincreasingthatfacedbyfirms,thusresultinginthesameallocations

.1

Theimplicationisthatwhileconsumerenergysubsidiescanbedesignedtoshieldhouseholdsfromariseintherelativepriceofenergy(sayduetoasupplyshock),suchapolicyisessentiallyataxonfirmsthatdrivesuptheirmarginalcostsofproduction.

Weshowhowalog-linearizedversionofthemodelwithenergycanbeexpressedinaformisomorphictothatof

Ercegetal.

(2000),andusethisformulationtoderiveastriking

analyticalresult.Inparticular,weshowthatenergysubsidiestoconsumersnecessarilyboostcorepriceinflationifmonetarypolicykeepsemploymentatpotentialandwagesareindexedtocoreinflation(eitherfullyorpartially,includingthespecialcaseofnoindexation).Thisresultholdsforanyconfigurationofparametersassumingthatveryweakconditionsaresat-isfied(i.e.,implyingthatadverseenergyshocksreducethepotentialrealwage).Intuitively,whileconsumersubsidiesdamptheinitialriseinheadlineinflation,thesubsidiesdriveuptheenergypricesfacedbyproducers,whichtheypassalonggraduallythroughraisingproductprices.Hence,thesesubsidiesmakeinflation–bothcoreandheadline–morepersistent.

Theclosedeconomymodelisrelevantforconsideringthelikelyeffectsofconsumerenergysubsidiesintheglobaleconomywhenallcountriespursuesimilarpolicies,orinahighlysegmentedenergymarket(suchasfornaturalgasinEurope).Inshort,wefindusingquantitativesimulationsofourmodelthatevenahighdegreeofindexationtoheadlineconsumerpriceinflation–wellabovewhatwefindempiricallyfortheUS,oreventheeuroarea–isnotenoughforconsumerenergysubsidiestoreducecoreinflation.Thesesubsidiesindeedreducefirst-roundeffectsonheadlineinflationinresponsetoanenergypricespikeandthisreducesupwardpressureonwages,buttheyalsocausethepre-subsidyenergypricefacedbyfirmstoriseenoughthatthe“all-in”effectisariseincoreinflation.Welfareanalysisusingtheusualutility-basedmetricconfirmsthatconsumerenergysubsidieslowerwelfare.

Whileourworkhorsemodelcastsstrongdoubtontheabilityofconsumersubsidiestolowerinflationwhenappliedglobally,itstillmightbeexpectedthatasmallopeneconomy–orgroupofcountriestoosmalltoaffectglobalenergyprices–mightbeabletousesubsidiestolowerinflation.Toexplorethis,weuseatwo-countryextensionwithincompleteassetmarkets.Thisvariantallowsforthetransmissionofenergysupplyshockstodiffersubstantiallyacrossenergy-importersandexporters,andalsodependonthedepthofthe

1Thesealternativeapproachesdohavedifferentimplicationsforthepre-subsidyenergyprice,withtheconsumersubsidydrivinguptheenergyprice,andthetaxonfirmsdrivingitdown(hence,allocationswouldbeaffectedinasettingwithendogenousoilproduction).

3

foreignexchangemarketwhichheavilyinfluencestheexchangerateresponse.

Focusingonthesmallopeneconomycase,wefindmorescopeforconsumerenergysubsidiestoreducecoreinflationthanintheclosedeconomymodel.Thisseemsintuitive:suchsubsidiesshould“chokeoff”firstroundeffectsandthuslimitthescopeforsecondroundeffectstomaterialize,includingthroughwageindexation.Andfirmsshouldnotbe“bitten”byhigherglobalenergypricesgiventhehomecountry’ssmallshareintheglobalenergymarket.

Evenso,theconditionsunderwhichsubsidiesreducecoreinflationstillturnouttobesurprisinglyrestrictive.Althoughsubsidieshaveessentiallynoeffectonglobalenergyprices,theycausethetradebalancetodeteriorateandexchangeratetodepreciate.Thisexchangeratechannelcanbebigenoughthatsubsidiescancausecoreinflationtorise,unlesswageindexationtoconsumerpricesissufficientlyhigh.

2

Thedepreciationeffectislargerthemorepersistentthesubsidy(whichtypicallyislinkedtothepersistenceoftheunderlyingshocktoenergysupply)andislargerineconomieswithshallowforeignexchangemarkets,asisthecaseinmanyemergingmarketeconomies.

Thepolicyimplicationisthatconsumerenergysubsidiesmayhelpreducecoreinflationifimplementedbycountriesthatarearelativelysmallshareoftheglobalenergymarket;ifthesubsidiesaretemporary;ifwageindexationtoconsumerpricesishigh(sothatsecondroundeffectswouldbelargeintheabsenceofsubsidies);andiftheactionsaretakenbyeconomieswithwell-developedfinancialmarketsandmodestdebtlevels.Theseconditionsalignwellwiththosethat

Daoetal.

(2023)foundinthecaseoftheeuroarea,wheretheyarguethat

consumerenergysubsidieshelpedmitigatebothheadlineandcoreinflationpressures

.3

Butasforeshadowedbytheclosedeconomyresults,ourtwocountrymodelhighlightshowconsumersubsidiesarelesslikelytobeeffectiveinreducinginflationastheirusebecomesmorewidespread.Thepre-subsidyenergypricerisesbymore,makingitmorelikelythatsubsidiesboostinflation.Moreover,ourmodelhighlightstheadversespilloverstootheren-ergyimporters–thelatterexperiencebiggertradedeficits,currencydepreciation,andupsideinflationpressure.Thespilloversareparticularlyacuteforvulnerableemergingeconomieswiththinforeignexchangemarkets.

Whileourfocusislargelyonaggregatesupply,consumerenergysubsidiesalsohavedemandsideeffectsthatmayvarysignificantlyacrosshouseholds,andwhicharenotwell-capturedbyourframework.Indeed,ourwelfareresultsinparticularmaybeviewedasundulybiasedagainstsuchsubsidiesinsofarthemodeldoesnotallowforhowsubsidiesmayshieldpoorerandliquidity-constrainedhouseholdsfrommajorhitstotheirpurchasingpowerandconsumptionarisingfromenergyshocks–whichwasclearlyakeyaimofpolicymakers

2Energysubsidiestendtobehelpfulundertheseconditionsbychokingofffirst-roundeffectsthatwouldotherwiseexertlargepassthroughtocore.

3Wealsoshowthatapackageofenergysubsidiestofirmsaswellashouseholdsmaybeattractiveforasmall“energy-pricetaking”economy–supportingaggregatedemandwhileloweringinflation.

inadditiontorestrainingoverallinflation.

Toexplorethis,weincorporatehand-to-mouthhouseholdsintoourclosedeconomymodelasinthetwo-agentNewKeynesian(TANK)setupdevelopedby

Galietal.

(2007)and

Bilbiie

(2008),andshowthatourresultsarelargelyrobustevenwhencapturingthedemand-sideef

-fectsofenergyshocks.

4

Interestingly,weshowthatconsumerenergysubsidiescouldimprovewelfareinourTANKframeworkbyreducingconsumptioninequalityacrosshouseholds(i.e.,permanentincomeversushand-to-mouth).However,targetedtransferstohand-to-mouthhouseholdsaremoreefficientastheycanachievethisgoalatlowerfiscalcostandwithabetterinflation-outputtradeoff.Themainadvantageofsuchtransfersoverenergysubsidiesisthattheydonotdistortrelativeenergypricesfacedbyhouseholds,andhencepreservetheirincentivetoconserveenergy.Thislimitstheincreaseinthepre-subsidyenergypricefacedbyfirms,andhencelowersinflationpressure.

Ourpaperiscloselyrelatedtoaninsightfulrecentpaperby

Auclertetal.

(2023)which

exploresthetransmissionofoilshocksinanopeneconomyHANKmodel,andtheeffectsofconsumerenergysubsidies.Theseauthorsalsoshowhowsubsidiesmaybebeneficialinreducinginflationandboostingconsumptionforanindividual“small”country,butcanhavecounterproductiveeffectsifdeployedbyabroadsetofcountries.Ourpaperdiffersfromtheirworkinseveralimportantaspects.First,theirpaperfocusesheavilyonheterogeneityacrosshouseholdsinaHANKframeworkandassociateddistributionaleffects,whereasourstudydevotesmuchmoreattentiontothesupplyside(differentwageindexationschemesratherthanassumingfullindexationofwagestoconsumerprices).Second,weincorporatefeaturesaimedatcapturingfinancialvulnerabilities(suchasthinFXmarkets)thatinfluencehowsubsidiesoperatethroughopeneconomychannels.Third,weassumethecentralbankfollowsoptimalpolicyorusesaTaylor-stylereactionfunctionthatprovidesagoodapproximation.Thisturnsouttohaveimportantimplicationsforthepass-throughofenergypriceshocksandsubsidies.Alltold,ourpaperismorepessimisticintheabilitytouseconsumerenergysubsidiessuccessfullytoreduceinflation,eveninthecaseofasmallgroupofcountries(e.g.,showinghowsubsidiescanbecounterproductivethroughtradechannels).

Ourpaperalsodrawsontheextensiveearlierliteraturestudyingthetransmissionofen-ergypriceshocks.Keyempiricalcontributionsinclude

Hamilton

(1983),

Hamilton

(2003),

BarskyandKilian

(2004),

BlanchardandGali

(2007),

Kilian

(2009),

BaumeisterandHamil-

ton

(2019),and

Ka¨nzig

(2021)

.Weuseenergysupplyshocksidentifiedinthislastpapertoanalyzethereactionofwages.Anumberofpapersincorporateenergyintostructuralmacroeconomicmodels,butdonotstudytheeffectsofenergysubsidies,see

KimandLoun-

gani

(1992),

BackusandCrucini

(2000),

LeducandSill

(2004),

Bodensteinetal.

(2011),

BlanchardandRiggi

(2013),

Bodensteinetal.

(2018),

BaqaeeandFarhi

(2019),

Gagliardone

4DebortoliandGali(2018)arguethatasimpletwo-agentNewKeynesian(TANK)modelcanbea

goodapproximationofheterogeneousagentNewKeynesian(HANK)modelsregardingthetransmissionof

aggregateshockstomacroeconomicvariables.

4

5

andGertler

(2023),and

Pieroni

(2023),amongothers.Similarlyto

Auclertetal.

(2023),the

lastpaperusesaHANKsetupwhileweoptforamoreparsimoniousTANKmodelasanextensiontocapturehouseholdheterogeneityandanalyzethescopefortransfers.BylookingattheinteractionsbetweenpriceandnominalwagerigiditywithinNewKeynesianmodels,ourworkisrelatedtotheliteratureoriginatedby

Blanchard

(1986)anddrawsparticularly

on

Ercegetal.

(2000)and

Bodensteinetal.

(2008).

Arecentcontributioninthislineby

LorenzoniandWerning

(2023)considersboththetransmissionofsupplyanddemandshocks

andoptimalpolicyinacontinuoustimeframework(withinflationinterpretedasarisingfromconflictbetweenfirmsandworkersoverwages).

Thepaperisstructuredasfollows.Section2discussestheempiricalevidenceontheeffectsofenergypriceshocks,withaspecialfocusontheresponseofwages.Section3presentsasimpleclosedeconomymodelwithenergy.Section4offersanalyticalinsightsonthetransmissionofenergypriceshocksandsubsidies.ThesearecomplementedwithquantitativesimulationsdescribedinSection5.Section6presentstheversionofthemodelwithhand-to-mouthagentsandisfollowedbyanopeneconomyextensioninSection7.Section8concludes.

2EmpiricalEvidenceonOilShocksandWageAdjustment

Inthissection,weprovideempiricalevidenceontheresponseofwagesandconsumerpricestooilpriceshocksintheUnitedStatesandtheeuroarea.

First,weidentifyasourceofoilpricemovementsthatisnotcorrelatedwithotherfun-damentalshockstoavoidreversecausalityoraomittedvariablebias.Todoso,werelyon

Ka¨nzig

(2021)whoidentifiessurprisechangesinoilfuturespricesrelatedtoOPEC’s

meetingsdecisionsaboutproductiontargets.AsKnzigmeasuresthesechangesinatight

windowaroundtheannouncements,

5

itislikelythattheycanisolatetheimpactonoilpricesoftheunexpectedcomponentofOPEC’sdeliberations–analogouslytotheliteraturethatidentifiesmonetarypolicyshocks(e.g.,

Gurkaynaketal.,

2005;

GertlerandKaradi,

2015;

NakamuraandSteinsson,

2018,amongothers).SincemarketspaycloseattentiontoOPEC’s

decisions,areversecausalityoftheglobaleconomicoutlookshouldplausiblyberuledoutbecauseitshouldalreadybepricedinatthetimeoftheannouncement.OPEC’sdecisions

arenotrandomeventsbutastheKnzigshocksmeasureonlythecomponentnotanticipated

bymarkets,theirimmediateimpactonpricesshouldreflecttheelementofthedecisionthatsurprisedmarketparticipants

.6

Adistinctadvantageofusingtheseshocksrelativetothe

5Thewindowistakentobeoneday,usingWTIcrudefuturesstartingin1983tradedattheNewYorkMercantileExchange(NYMEX),whichisoneofthemostliquidandlargestmarketforcrudeoil.Forfurtherdetails,see

Ka¨nzig

(2021)

.

6NazerandPescatori

(2022)showthatitisthesurprisecomponentoftheOPEC(orOPEC+)decisions

thataffectsthemarketsincethesamedecisioncaninducepriceresponsesofdifferentsign.

6

standardapproachpioneeredby

Kilian

(2009)istobypassthedifficultiesofdisentangling

oildemandandoilproductionshocks.Evenso,wewillshowthatourresultsalsoholdwhenusingshocksmeasuredby

BaumeisterandHamilton

(2019)

.

Theseriesofoilpricesurprisesspanningfrom1983to2019areaggregatedatquarterlyfrequencyandusedasaninstrumentinanSVARmodel.Inadditiontothestandardoilmarketvariablessuchasrealoilprices(deflatedbyeithercoreorheadlineprices),oilproduction,andglobalindustrialproduction,ourproxySVARmodelalsoincludesrealGDP,coreorheadlineCPIinflation,theshort-termpolicyrate,aswellasnominalwageinflation.Allquantitiesandrelativepricesareinlogs,thepolicyratesinpercentagepoints,whilepriceandwageinflationaremeasuredaslogdifferences.WeuseidenticalSVARspecificationsfortheUSandtheeuroarea.Appendices

A.1

and

A.2

containadditionaldetailsontheproxySVARanddatadefinitions.

OurbaselineresultsarereportedinFigures

1

and

2

fortheUSandeuroarea,respectively.AccordingtotheproxySVARfortheUS,anincreaseinoilpricesdrivenbyanoilsupplynewsshockleadstoadeclineinnominalandrealwages.

7

Moreconcretely,anoilsupply-driven10percentincreaseinoilpriceswitha2-yearhalflifeincreasescoreinflationbyabout0.1percentagepointforafewquartersandreducesthenominalwagebyabout0.2percentonimpact.Consequently,theimpliedproducerrealwage–calculatedbyaccumulatingthenominalwagegrowthimpulsesandsubtractingtheaccumulatedcoreinflationimpulses–fallsbyroughly0.3percentoverthefirst2yearsandbynearly0.6percentafter5years.ThereductioninrealwagesisinlinewithanoilsupplyshocktransmittingsimilarlytoanadverseTFPshock,withrealGDPfallingbymorethat0.4percentafter2years.Cruciallyforourfurtheranalysis,theseresultssuggeststhattheabilityofUShouseholdsandlaborunionstoachievecompensationforhigherpricesthroughhigherwagesisverylimited.

TheimpactontheeuroareaisshowninFigure

2.

WhiletheoilpricepathisalmostidenticaltothatobtainedintheSVARfortheUS,thetransmissiontootherkeymacrovariablesdiffersnotably.Mostnotably,nominalwagegrowthpersistentlyincreases.ThisfindingispossiblydrivenbymorecentralizedwagebargainingandhigherunionizationintheeuroareathanintheUS,leadingtoahigherdegreeof(explicitorimplicit)indexation

(BabaandLee,

2022)

.IncreasingwagesputsomeupwardpressureoncoreinflationandsotheECBraisestheinterestratesignificantly.ThetighterpolicystanceimpliesthattheassociatedoutputcontractionisaboutthesameasintheUS,althoughtheeuroareaeconomyislessdependentonoil.Turningtotheimpliedrealproducerwage,thepointestimateofitsimpulseresponseismodestlypositive,butnotsignificantlyso.WeinterpretthisfindingasonlymildevidenceinfavorofsomeindexationmechanismsinEuropeanwagesettingthatcompensateshouseholdsforthelossofpurchasingpowerduetoenergypriceshocks.

7Theconfidencebandsarecomputedusingamovingblockbootstrap,asproposedby

JentschandLunsford

(2019).Thismethodproducesasymptoticallyvalidconfidencebandsunderfairlymildalpha-mixingcondi

-tions.Theblocksizeissetto24anddealswiththedifferenceintheestimationandidentificationsamples.

7

Figure1:USProxy-VAREvidence:OilPriceShocks

Notes:Allvariablesareexpressedinpercentdeviations,realoilpricesaredeflatedwithcoreCPI,impliedrealwageisdefinedasaccumulatednominalwageinflationminuscoreinflation.Theconfidencebandsarethe68and90percentlevelbandsbasedon10,000bootstrapreplications.

8

Figure2:EAProxy-VAREvidence:OilPriceShocks

Notes:Allvariablesareexpressedinpercentdeviations,realoilpricesaredeflatedwithcoreCPI,impliedrealwageisdefinedasaccumulatednominalwageinflationminuscoreinflation.Theconfidencebandsarethe68and90percentlevelbandsbasedon10,000bootstrapreplications.

AsshowninAppendix

A.3

,theimpactofanoilsupplyshockonheadlineinflationisnotablystrongeronimpactinboththeUSandtheeuroarea,upto1(0.5)percentinthe

9

samequarterbutmuchlesspersistent–consistentlywithoilpricesrevertingtotheirpre-shocklevels.Evenso,theimpliedconsumerrealwage,i.e.nominalwagedividedbyheadlineCPI,fallsnotablymoreinitiallythantheproducerrealwageinFigure

1

.Thesmallerpass-throughtoheadlineinflationrelativetocoreinflationintheeuroareathanintheUScanbeatleastpartiallyexplainedbyhigherexcisetaxesonliquidfuelsandadownstreamoil

industrythattendstohavemorerigidretailprices(Ahn,

2024).Importantlyforourfurther

analysis,regardlessifweworkwithcoreorheadlineinflationintheSVAR,wefindthattheimpliedrealwageintheeuroareafallslessthanintheUS.

WehaveexaminedtherobustnessofourresultsforanumberofalternativeSVARspec-ifications.Figure

3

presentstheimpulseresponsesfortheimpliedproducerrealwage(USintheleftcolumnandeuroareaintheright),whileAppendix

A.3

reportstheresultsforallvariablesincludedineachoftheconsideredalternatives.ThefirstrowinthefigurejustrestatesourbaselineresultsfromFigures

1

and

2.

Thesecondrowreportsanalternativewhereweimposemeanreversionoftherealwageimpulseresponsesbyintroducingthisvari-abledirectlyintheSVARinsteadofnominalwagegrowthandimposingstabilityconditions.Ascanbeseen,realproducerwagesintheUSstilldeclinesignificantlyinresponsetoanenergysupplyshockwhiletheyrisesomewhat(althoughnotsignificantlyatthe90percentconfidencelevel)inEurope.

Wealsotestedforpossiblenon-linearitiesintracingtheeffectsofoilpriceshoc

温馨提示

  • 1. 本站所有资源如无特殊说明,都需要本地电脑安装OFFICE2007和PDF阅读器。图纸软件为CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.压缩文件请下载最新的WinRAR软件解压。
  • 2. 本站的文档不包含任何第三方提供的附件图纸等,如果需要附件,请联系上传者。文件的所有权益归上传用户所有。
  • 3. 本站RAR压缩包中若带图纸,网页内容里面会有图纸预览,若没有图纸预览就没有图纸。
  • 4. 未经权益所有人同意不得将文件中的内容挪作商业或盈利用途。
  • 5. 人人文库网仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对用户上传分享的文档内容本身不做任何修改或编辑,并不能对任何下载内容负责。
  • 6. 下载文件中如有侵权或不适当内容,请与我们联系,我们立即纠正。
  • 7. 本站不保证下载资源的准确性、安全性和完整性, 同时也不承担用户因使用这些下载资源对自己和他人造成任何形式的伤害或损失。

评论

0/150

提交评论